Mean-Variance Portfolio Theory: A Structured Overview
This post outlines the core concepts of Modern Portfolio Theory (MPT), blending mathematical rigor with intuitive interpretation.
Table of Contents
- 1. Portfolio Structure and Notation
- 2. Expected Return and Variance
- 3. Mean-Variance Utility and Optimization
- 4. Efficient Frontier and Capital Market Line
1. Portfolio Structure and Notation
Asset Universe
\[S = \{s_1, s_2, \dots, s_N\}\]This represents the set of assets under consideration, including stocks, bonds, and alternative investments.
Weight Vector
\[W = \begin{bmatrix} w_1 \\ w_2 \\ \vdots \\ w_N \end{bmatrix}, \quad \sum_{i=1}^N w_i = 1,\quad w_i \ge 0\]Each $w_i$ indicates the fraction of capital allocated to asset $s_i$.
The weights must sum to 1, assuming full investment.
Short-selling is not allowed under these constraints.
Portfolio Return
\[R = \begin{bmatrix} R_1 \\ R_2 \\ \vdots \\ R_N \end{bmatrix}, \quad R_p = W^T R = \sum_{i=1}^N w_i R_i\]The total portfolio return is the weighted average of the individual asset returns.
2. Expected Return and Variance
Expected Return
\[\mathbb{E}[R_p] = \sum_{i=1}^N w_i \mu_i = W^T \mu\]Here, $ \mu_i = \mathbb{E}[R_i] $ is the expected return of asset $s_i$, and $ \mu $ is the vector of expected returns across all assets.
Portfolio Variance
\[\text{Var}(R_p) = W^T \Sigma W = \sum_{i=1}^N \sum_{j=1}^N w_i w_j \sigma_{ij}\]$ \Sigma $ is the covariance matrix of asset returns.
The variance of the portfolio accounts for both the individual risks and the correlations between assets.
3. Mean-Variance Utility and Optimization
A risk-averse investor seeks to achieve the highest possible return for a given level of risk.
This trade-off can be modeled using the mean-variance utility function:
The parameter $A > 0$ captures the investor’s risk aversion.
A higher value of $A$ reflects greater sensitivity to risk.
Optimization Problem
\[\begin{aligned} \max_W \quad & W^T \mu - \frac{A}{2} W^T \Sigma W \\ \text{s.t.} \quad & \mathbf{1}^T W = 1, \quad W \succeq 0 \end{aligned}\]This problem identifies the weight vector $W$ that maximizes the investor’s utility
while satisfying the constraints of full investment and no short-selling.
4. Efficient Frontier and Capital Market Line
Figure 1. Efficient Frontier and Capital Market Line
Source: Wikipedia – Efficient Frontier
By solving the optimization problem for various values of the risk aversion parameter $A$,
we can generate a set of optimal portfolios.
These portfolios collectively form the Efficient Frontier,
which represents the highest expected return achievable at each level of risk.
Each point on the frontier corresponds to a portfolio that is not dominated in terms of risk and return.
In other words, no other portfolio offers a higher return for the same level of risk.
When a risk-free asset with return $R_f$ becomes available, investors can construct new portfolios by combining the risk-free asset with a portfolio on the efficient frontier.
The resulting combinations lie along a straight line known as the Capital Market Line (CML):
The slope of this line, given by $ \frac{\mu_M - R_f}{\sigma_M} $, is known as the Sharpe Ratio, which indicates the excess return earned per unit of risk.